Are Australian trade unions part of the solution, or part of the problem?

David Peetz, Griffith University

In recent years, there has been growing recognition of the failure of the modern economy to deliver widespread benefits for all. Instead, since the 1980s, Australia—like many other advanced industrialised countries—has experienced rising inequality and a growing concentration of income, wealth and power in a small group sometimes referred to as ‘the one per cent’ or, more accurately, ‘the 0.1 per cent’ (Murray & Peetz 2013; Piketty 2014). The profit share of national income has consistently risen at the expense of the wages share since the 1980s, in Australia and elsewhere (Ellis & Smith 2007), while top incomes including chief executive officer (CEO) salaries, have outpaced wages and contributed to widening inequality (Atkinson & Leigh 2007; Frydman & Saks 2005; Murray & Peetz 2013). Before the global financial crisis, members of the financial elite spoke of the rise of ‘plutonomy’, an economy ‘powered by the wealthy’, particularly in the English-speaking industrialised societies (Kapur, Macleod & Singh 2005). In countries with high shares of income going to the very top, inter-generational mobility is lower, (Brunori, Ferreira & Peragine 2013; Krueger 2012), child poverty is higher (Mishel, Bernstein & Shierholz 2009; Stilwell & Jordan 2007); and health and social problems are worse (Wilkinson & Pickett 2009). In this world, ordinary workers—those in the middle and lower parts of the income ranges—have limited access to resources and even more limited effective say.

Within the workplace, from the 1980s working hours have increased in Australia and some other countries (Campbell 2002), as has the intensity of work (Green 2004; Griffith Work Time Project 2003), and work-life balance has been under strain (Baker, Johnson & Denniss 2014; Pocock, Skinner & Ichii 2009), with adverse implications for health and family wellbeing (Denniss & Baker 2012; Griffith Work Time Project 2003; Shepanski and Diamond 2007). Consequently, many people in many countries want shorter full-time working hours (Anxo, Franz & Kümmerling 2012). As female participation in the labour market has increased, we have not seen a reduction in care demands on women or in hours demanded of male employees but rather an increase in demands on women’s time (Skinner & Pocock 2014). ‘Overemployment’ has thus grown alongside unemployment and underemployment. Insecurity has expanded in most countries, including through the spread of casual work, ‘independent’ contracting or other forms of peripheral employment (Campbell & Burgess 2001), leading to the growth of the ‘precariat’—workers in informal or casual jobs (Standing 2011). Greater flexibility is demanded of employees, shifting risk from capital to labour (Rafferty & Yu 2010). Monitoring in some industries enables supervisors to manage workers’ activities to seconds (Callaghan & Thompson 2001; O’Connor 2013; Wright & Lund 1996), while in others, managerial efforts to ‘strengthen’ or control ‘culture’ within organisation have sought to manage not just what workers do, but also what they think (Tourish, Collinson & Barker 2009; Van den Broek 1997; Willmott 1993). Worker power is reduced. Managers often restrict employee say in decisions to that narrow range of issues where they foresee gains in profitability from increased employee input.

Australian unions helped maintain workers’ share of national income during the 20th century.

This redistribution of incomes and power has accompanied the spread and adoption to varying degrees of ‘market liberal’ or ‘neoliberal’ economic policies in almost all industrialised countries. The stated aim has been to improve economic efficiency and performance, through boosting growth in productivity and per capita gross domestic product (GDP). Yet over this period, there has been no noticeable improvement in productivity, either in Australia or globally (Peetz 2012). During the WorkChoices years, when ‘neoliberal’ reform reached its maximum potential (though still with extensive state controls over what employees or their organisations could do) (Peetz & Bailey 2011)), productivity growth slumped (Peetz 2012). Productivity growth has moved closer to long term trends under the Fair Work Act, but there is no sign of our sustainably surpassing the rates achieved in the years preceding market liberal reforms of awards, labour markets and product markets. Meanwhile, and curiously, public debate in Australia proceeds as if there were a fiscal ‘mess’ in Australia comparable to that in Europe. Yet none exists: net public debt as a proportion of GDP is one sixth the average across advanced industrialised countries (International Monetary Fund 2013). Still, workers and others outside ‘the one per cent’ are expected to pay to ‘clean’ up this ‘mess’.

HOW HAVE UNIONS CONTRIBUTED IN THE PAST TO THE SOLUTION?

The situation as described above was not always so. Through much of the twentieth century from the 1910s, and particularly in the three decades up to the 1970s, inequality and the share of the ‘one per cent’ declined (Atkinson & Leigh 2007; Piketty 2014). The profit share was relatively stable (in Australia, aside from a shift caused by the ‘wages explosion’ of the early 1970s). The ratio of CEO pay to workers pay was stable or even narrowing (Frydman & Saks 2005; Murray & Peetz 2013). And, importantly, union membership was high.

During this period, Australian unions helped maintain workers’ share by campaigning for wage increases and improvements in conditions of employment by making strategic use of the arbitration system. A portion of the unionised workforce would successfully agitate for improvements in wage or conditions, either through direct negotiation with employers or through advocacy in a tribunal, and then use the tribunal system to spread the gains through the rest of the workforce. Gains might be achieved through national tribunal cases, often building on precedents in particular sectors. Unions also used their links with the Australian Labor Party (ALP), originally created by unions in the 1890s, to secure passage of legislation or the creation of administrative arrangements favourable to workers when the ALP was in government at state or federal level (Peetz & Bailey 2011; Peetz & Bailey 2012). Conversely, union ties to the ALP made unions vulnerable to legislative attack if a conservative government saw this as a means of weakening its political opponent. Overall, though, the membership levels and the industrial and political strategies of the unions gave workers—both members and non-members—substantial gains through much of the twentieth century.

These contributed to the moderation of inequality through this period. A series of studies showed that, across countries, higher union density tended to be associated with lower levels of inequality (Card, Lemieux & Riddell 2003; Freeman 2005; Freeman & Medoff 1984; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 1997), by affecting wages, especially for lower–paid workers (Mishel & Walters 2003) and also such things as the adoption of equal opportunity practices within firms (Hoque & Bacon 2014). It is likely that other factors are relevant too. For example, a society with a strong ethos of egalitarianism is likely both to encourage governments to enact policies that reduce inequality and to permit or facilitate the emergence of a large, effective trade union movement. On the other hand, social values do not emerge from nowhere, and it is also likely that powerful union movements play a role in promoting egalitarian values (Western & Rosenfeld 2011).

In the early 1980s, in response to the persistence of ‘stagflation’ (simultaneous inflation and unemployment), the ALP and Australian unions negotiated a prices and incomes Accord that would shape wages policy and many other areas through the ALP’s 1983–1996 term in government. During this period, however, there were also concerted attacks on unions by employers and conservative state governments, as in many other countries, in no small part due to employer responses to changes in product markets arising from market liberal reforms. Structural change in the 1980s had shifted employment away from union-dense industries. In the 1990s this force was overtaken by the influence of government and employer actions, with the new conservative Howard Government weighing in during the second half of the 1990s (Peetz 1998). A long-successful solution became the problem. Unions’ highly developed capacities for industrial advocacy and for doing politics—at least politics with the ALP, with which they had deep financial and membership links—became a liability in a system where wage fixing had shifted from awards to ‘enterprise bargaining’ and the workplace, not the tribunal, became the centre of action. By the end of the 1990s, union density had slumped to less than half its level of the 1960s or 1970s.

In response to this decline, unions sought to reorganise themselves, with varying degrees of enthusiasm and incomplete effects, devoting more resources to the workplace and sometimes to the training or education of delegates, and diverting resources away from tribunal advocacy and ‘servicing’ of members (Peetz & Bailey 2012). Enthusiasm and success varied between and within unions and union branches. This reorganisation boosted the power in unions in some workplaces but the external environment continued to be highly unfavourable. Still, unions were able in 1998 to withstand a co-ordinated attack—probably a ‘conspiracy’ at law, as claimed by union lawyers, though this was only partially tested in the courts—involving the federal government and a major waterfront employer. The attack involved mass redundancies and the replacement of the unionised workforce, and was aimed at crippling the iconic Maritime Union of Australia (MUA). Although the settlement involved several hundred redundancies, the MUA survived, partially achieving the employer’s objective of increased productivity but denying the government’s objective of waterfront deunionisation (McConville 2000; Peetz 1999; Wiseman 1998).

Structural change in the 1980s had shifted employment away from union-dense industries.

A major success of the union movement came in 2006–07, through its Your Rights at Work campaign, which ultimately was a key factor in the defeat of the Howard Government (Muir 2008; Muir & Peetz 2010; Wilson & Spies-Butcher 2011). The government had taken advantage of an unexpected majority in the Senate and enacted ‘WorkChoices’ legislation with effect from early 2006, designed to remove many aspects of the safety net for workers, both on pay and dismissal protection, and to critically weaken trade unions. The Australian Council of Trade Unions (ACTU) designed and co-ordinated a campaign combining elements of the workplace organising principles of industrial campaigning it had been developing with sophisticated polling, marketing and publicity techniques. The campaign was aimed at building up sufficient opposition to WorkChoices to defeat the government at the 2007 election. In this it succeeded, and in defeating an incumbent government, the Australian union movement achieved what few other union movements since the turn of the century have achieved (or, to be fair, needed to achieve). In this the union movement became a central part of a solution to some of the problems identified above—albeit briefly. But it was not to last.

HOW ARE UNIONS NOW PART OF THE PROBLEM?

If unions were once part of a solution, then their decline and the problems they face in arresting that decline now constitute part of the problem itself—their situation is a barrier to redressing the growth in inequality. Although many unions have undertaken internal reforms, few have been transformed. In the 1990s Barbara Pocock referred to ‘institutional sclerosis’ within unions and, while it is important not to understate the changes that unions have undergone, it is also important not to understate the magnitude of the even greater changes demanded of them.

Unions remain a shadow of their former selves, now representing approximately seventeen per cent of the workforce (Australian Bureau of Statistics 2013). Although the membership decline was stabilised by the early 2000s, it subsequently failed to grow at a sufficient rate to match the growth in the workforce, so density has continued to ease. For a while it appeared that density might start to increase, but the latest estimates published by the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), based on a large household survey, suggest a further decline. Sampling error, and the movement of this collection from annual to biennial, make it difficult to interpret this most recent movement against the previous trend.

With low density, Australian unions are in a limited position to counter the causes of rising inequality and declining worker power. The increase in inequality in several countries has been linked in part to the decline in union density (Card, Lemieux & Riddell 2003; Charlwood 2007; Pontusson 2013; Western & Rosenfeld 2011), including through unions’ reduced role ‘in the workings of government’ (Gage 2014; Noah 2010). Changes in US union density closely track changes in the share of the top one per cent, but the relationship is less striking in Canada or Australia (Murray & Peetz 2013). It is now claimed that US unions no longer do four key things they once did: equalise incomes, counteract racial inequality, help assimilate migrants, or give lower income earners a voice (Fox 2014).

Here, it is clear that Australian unions are in a much weaker situation than during the Accord years. In an economy with many poorly competitive product markets, especially in relation to overseas-produced goods, there were opportunities for parts of both labour and capital to extract ‘rents’—incomes above what perfectly competitive markets would deliver. This competition for rents became a spiral that heightened the problems of simultaneous unemployment and inflation. That is what prompted the Accord: unions’ ability to influence rents and macroeconomic outcomes gave them a central seat at the national bargaining table in the 1980s.

These days rents are still being extracted, but by different groups—principally extremely high income earners, the chief executive officers, directors and managers of top firms, and parts of the finance sector. In an economy characterised by more competitive product markets and weaker union density, unions do not play a major role in rent extraction any more. Yesterday’s problem of general price and wage inflation (and of responding to it) has been superseded by the narrower inflation of executive remuneration and of the incomes of the rich (especially the top 0.1 per cent) and asset price bubbles. Market liberal ‘reforms’ have not solved our economic problems and delivered an acceleration of our growth in wellbeing. They have just changed the problems, and in doing so made life more difficult for many workers.

By the Rudd-Gillard years, unions were relegated to the role of just another interest lobby group. In negotiating and finalising the drafting of the Fair Work Act, unions had a role neither larger nor smaller than that of organised business groups. Within the parameters of Labor’s election promises (Rudd & Gillard 2007), the final version of the legislation included some good outcomes for unions but as many for business (including a breach of the election promise to allow agreements to cover all matters). By contrast, when the Brereton Industrial Relations Reform Act 1993 was being written, unions were at the table in a formal working group established under the Accord processes; business was a lobby group whose interests merely had to be taken into account.

Although many unions have undertaken internal reforms, few have been transformed.

Unions have maintained their links with the Labor Party, links that originated with the party’s formation. Yet after 2007 unions were often ignored by the ALP government, particularly by comparison with the Accord period of the 1980s and 1990s. The ALP government acted as if it figured, fairly rightly, ‘where else could unions go?’ Overall, that government probably spent considerably more time courting business than unions. A noticeable part of the time of union officials is taken up with internal ALP politics. A noticeable part of ALP leaders’ time is put into managing debates about whether and perhaps how union influence within the ALP should be contained. Unions’ narrower focus—it was not always so narrow—and their ties to the Labor Party—once part of the solution—appear now part of the problem. Unions put resources into the ALP, which badly needs the resources but does not want the unions, rather than putting resources into alternative institutions for advancing their interests (which might be left-leaning research bodies, social movements, political parties or coalition building amongst these and others).

Unlike the 1950s, where unions had viable choices as to whether they aligned their interests with the ALP or outside (in particular, with the Communist Party), there is no such alternative today readily used by unions. Very few have links to the Greens and where they do it is controversial (Crook 2013; Nolan 2014), while many in the Greens hesitate to align themselves too closely with an interest group that has been seen in the past to place jobs ahead of the environment. Meanwhile some in ALP leadership roles detest the Greens—as illustrated by Prime Minister Kevin Rudd’s eventually fatal refusal to negotiate with them over an emissions trading scheme (Daley 2010)—and this places further barriers between them and unions, especially the blue collar unions who have predominantly belonged to the ALP. This is not to argue the benefits of closer unions-Greens links, but simply to critique the narrow range of options unions provide themselves.

Unionism is no longer a primarily male, blue-collar affair. Women are now slightly more likely to belong to unions than men, and soon there will be more female unionists than male unionists. White-collar unionists now out-number blue-collar unionists by two to one. In 1992, professionals accounted for only about sixteen per cent of trade union members. By 2013, they accounted for 32 per cent and were, by far, the biggest occupational group amongst trade unionists (next were ‘Technicians and trades workers’ and ‘Community and personal service workers’, both with thirteen per cent). The biggest factor in the growth of unionised professionals was the rise of education and health professionals, whose combined share of unionists expanded from fourteen per cent in 1996 to 25 per cent in 2013. Many (78 per cent) are women. At the same time, the combined share of labourers, machinery and plant operators and drivers has fallen from around 27 per cent to nineteen per cent. Many (83 per cent) are men (Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014).

Manufacturing, once seen as the heartland of unionism, now accounts for only around seven per cent of unionists. The share of unionists employed in health care and social assistance has grown from eleven per cent in 1996 to nineteen per cent in 2013. It is now the largest industry group. Education’s share has also grown, albeit less spectacularly, from thirteen per cent to eighteen per cent.

The composition of the union movement is changing in other significant ways. In 1990, only around thirteen per cent of unionists were part-time workers; by 2013, 25 per cent of unionists were. Women’s higher density than men’s reflects their higher share of public sector employment (where density is higher), more than offsetting the effect of women’s over-representation amongst casual employees. Women’s growth in their share of unionists has occurred despite the shrinking of the public sector and the levelling of casual and part-time employment growth, but alongside the growth in female labour force participation and the greater decline in male density.

All these changes in composition are important for union policy and strategy. Many of what once were considered the ‘heartlands’ of unionism are no longer so. And wherever the heartland of unionism is, it cannot be said that unionism is the heartland of the workforce.

Governance remains an issue. While the degree of misbehaviour amongst union leaders and officials might be no worse than in the corporate or not-for-profit sectors (we really cannot tell), any instances have been highlighted by the government and media and portrayed as representing a generalised problem across unions. Considerable union resources have been tied up with the Royal Commission on Trade Union Governance and Corruption and more will be devoted to responding to the policy and publicity fall-out. There are well-argued claims that the Commission’s proceedings demonstrate bias against unions (Gordon 2014; Lyons 2014; Schneiders 2014; Workplace Express 2014), though there is also no doubt that some corruption existed within some unions. To the extent that certain union officials enriched themselves and disenfranchised members, this anti-democratic activity would have weakened workplace unionism, given the importance of perceptions of democracy for building workplace union power (Peetz & Pocock 2009). In the broader public, the annual Roy Morgan survey of perceptions of honesty and ethical behaviour in professions, found a one-third drop in positive scores for ‘union leaders’ over three years (from eighteen per cent of respondents giving ‘high’ or ‘very high’ ratings in 2011 to twelve per cent in 2014) (Roy Morgan Research 2014), following a sustained period of improvement in perceptions of union leaders after the lows of the early 1980s (Peetz 2002). On the other hand, trust in ‘trade unions’, as measured by Essential Media (Essential Media Communications 2015), has not changed much over three years. The challenge for governance of unions is how to be demonstrably pure without also appearing impotent. This is in part because the genesis of the Royal Commission appeared part of a broader attack by the conservative parties upon the power of trade unions (Lyons 2014).

Unionism is no longer a primarily male, blue-collar affair.

All this has happened against the backdrop of a need for major rethinking of economic and social policy, in Australia and overseas. When the global financial crisis pushed millions out of work globally, the rationale for market liberal policies was demolished. Yet the ideas behind market liberalism have persisted—like zombies (Quiggin 2010). Within two years Europe was plunged into austerity politics as market liberals successfully persuaded policy-makers that governments, not banks, were to blame and that workers, not the beneficiaries, needed to endure years of austerity to pay for other people’s fiscal mess. Even in Australia, with its small public debt, the rhetoric of austerity retains salience. More than anything else, this demonstrated the remarkable failure of civil society—in particular, unions and other bodies representing workers, children, the environment and the poor—to develop and articulate an alternative policy vision to challenge the failed market liberal paradigm. It was a great moment lost.

How can unions be part of the future solution?

The problems that workers face are not processes that can continue indefinitely. Eventually increases in work intensity or working hours become unsustainable. Resistance grows, some of it providing opportunity for co-ordination though unions and industrial action, some of it remaining unorganised but causing problems for employers through absenteeism, quits, losses in loyalty, problems in the quality of output, possibly even sabotage.

Even the effects of globalisation are not set in stone. On the one hand, it promotes economic development and the growth of employment, incomes and job security in developing and other countries. On the other hand, it promotes greater competition between corporations and nation states and, through that, greater demands for flexibility and downward pressure on wages and job security. The net effect of these two tendencies depends on the policy choices taken by states and the mobilisations by employers, unions and other parts of civil society that determine the conditions under which globalisation proceeds. But how much capacity will unions have to shape these economic forces and mobilise workers’ responses?

Power resources and capabilities

Canadian researchers, Lévesque and Murray, point out, the ‘key factors currently challenging union power clearly cut across the different national institutional arrangements in which unions are embedded’ (2010, p. 345). Australian unions are not unique in the problems they face, though specific national factors (such as the former reliance on arbitration) have exacerbated the problems here. Lévesque and Murray identify four key ‘power resources’ for unions (2010, pp. 336–340):

  1. internal solidarity (sufficiently cohesive identities to pursue their goals; and ‘deliberative vitality’ the participation of members in the life of their union);
  2. network embeddedness (the degree to which unions are linked to their own and other union organisations, community groups, social movements or other types of actors);
  3. narrative resources (the range of values, shared understandings, stories and ideologies that aggregate identities and interests, translate and inform motives and create a sense of efficacy (see Bandura 1995, 1997)), that frame understandings and union actions; and
  4. infrastructural resources (material, human, processes, policies and programs).

However, they argue that resources alone are not enough—unions must be capable of using them as the context changes. For example, intensified competition and globalisation has weakened pattern bargaining and links to political processes so that ‘external solidarity resources derived from previous patterns of network embeddedness are not providing the leverage on which past patterns of union action relied’ (Lévesque & Murray 2010, p. 345). This increases the importance of the workplace, while highlighting unions’ need to develop new ways of organising beyond the workplace and articulating back to it including through developing new forms of networks. One illustration is the increasing (though still limited) use by unions of social media (White 2010) and online actions (LabourStart 2014). As ‘understanding “ union resources and capabilities is critical to an understanding of efforts to enhance union power’, Lévesque and Murray (2010, pp. 341–345) also identified key four strategic capabilities required for union power.

Workplace power for unions requires workplace activism.

The first is framing—the ability to put forward an agenda that can be more or less inclusive and can be part of a broader social project. A major element of the successful ‘Your Rights at Work’ campaign was the way it was framed in terms of ‘rights’ (Muir 2008), but one of the major failings of progressive groups has been in adequately framing political debate and union rhetoric about inequality (Shenker-Osorio 2012). Framing is a major challenge when the media are replete with stories—some beat-ups, some fictional and some based on grim facts—about poor union governance, misbehaviour or corruption.

The second key capability is to intermediate between contending interests to foster collaborative action and to activate networks. On this matter, the Your Rights at Work campaign failed in one of its more ambitious objectives. While much has been said about the importance of community campaigning (for example, Tattersall 2010), and the emphasis given this in the Your Rights at Work campaign (Muir 2008), the campaign failed to deeply engage community groups and build strong linkages with them (Peetz & Bailey 2012).

The third capability is learning—the ability to reflect on and learn from past and current change in contexts, and organisational practices and routines, in order to anticipate and act upon change, and to spread these lessons throughout the organisation. Years of observing unions suggest to me that, while many individuals there are great learners, it is not so clear that the organisations as a whole fit that category—an observation seemingly still salient since Pocock made similar remarks not long after the start of unions’ reform process (Pocock 1998).

The fourth is to articulate actions over time (short term versus long term) and over space (managing the multiple levels at which unions seek to exert an influence and how they develop the interactions between these levels). Critical here is the link between the paid and unpaid levels of the union—between the office and the workplace. Effective union mobilisation requires power and capabilities on many levels. But perhaps the first of these, the foundation, is the workplace.

Building workplace organisation and democratisation

Workplace power for unions requires workplace activism. Workplace activism requires effective delegates; workplaces without active delegates were those most likely to be deunionised during the period of most rapid union decline in the early to mid-1990s (Peetz 1998). Activism also requires delegates with a sense of efficacy, as confidence and self-belief is a strong predictor of activism, even stronger than self-assessed skill levels (Peetz, Webb & Jones 2002). Workplace power requires support by the union office, particularly organisers, for workplace delegates (Peetz & Pocock 2009). While unions are more than just a form of workplace social capital (Nissen & Jarley 2005), workplace power requires delegates have access to networks, internal and external to the workplace, formalised or informal, that provide support, information and ideas. And it requires that delegates, and members, have a sense that they can and do influence what the union itself does. Democracy within unions is a precondition for success. It is not just a question of a union’s power for its members depending in part on power over its members (Hyman 1975, p. 65); in a world without wage arbitration, workers cannot have power in the workplace if they don’t have power in the union (Peetz & Pocock 2009).

Some of the implications, of what unions need to do to value and empower delegates, are obvious but not always easy. The research shows that activism is severely hampered unless workplace delegates are trained. Setting aside resources for education promotes learning within and by organisations. Training enhances not only the skills but also the confidence of delegates for engaging in activism (Peetz, Webb & Jones 2002). Delegates need to be trained on how to spread the load, to make use of other potential activists in the workplace who may have different but complementary capabilities or interests. The research also shows that formal training of delegates is almost wasted if resources are not also put into the follow-up of training, to imprint the lessons. The formal and the informal are two very important sides of the training coin (Peetz & Alexander 2013). Devoting resources to training is expensive but not so controversial; the structural changes needed to ensure it is followed up and complemented can be both. The provision and facilitation of opportunities for networking is as important for developing supportive networks for delegate networks as is the provision of training itself.

To be capable and motivated, delegates require both training and meaning from the union. By ‘meaning’ I refer to a sense of what the union stands for, through an articulation of union values through the union organisation (Lévesque & Murray 2002, 2010). I also refer to a sense of real say in the decisions that affect delegates and members, both direct participation in decision-making (influencing the day to day decisions about work as a member and delegate) and indirect participation (influencing the decisions of the union itself).

Can unions mobilise outside labour?

Democratisation, in this context, is not just about having elected structures. Generally, and on average, elected structures are good. However they do not have much impact if people are elected to positions unopposed, along factional lines. Sometimes, some forms of elected positions (such as elected organisers in some unions) can retard reform processes within unions and maintain the status quo.

Democratisation is more about how much ability members and delegates have, to shape what the union does. It is about how a union functions, and how open it is to members’ preferences and their diversity. The correlates of perceived democracy within unions suggest it is closely related to a willingness of the union to embrace and respond to broad constituencies, both inside and outside, such as those representing women’s interests (Peetz & Pocock 2007).

Unions in society

An effective response to the workplace and national problems and tendencies we experience requires a new way of doing things and of thinking about things—a new vision and new policy approaches. Unions, other social movements representing women, the underprivileged, community groups and the environment need to be drawn together with intellectuals into a major conversation if an alternative vision is to be developed, articulated and implemented. The prominence given to Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the 21st Century (Wade 2014) is not so much a reflection of a great new revelation as it is of the fact that the book ‘suits the mood of the times’ (Quiggin 2014). Piketty’s moment is a moment for progressive social movements at large.

In Australia the almost forgotten Accord between unions and the government of the 1980s was many things, some of which are now irrelevant. But most importantly it was an alternative vision of the economy, a challenge to the liberal market orthodoxy of government departments of the day. The need to develop an alternative vision of what the economy, society and workplace should look like is greater now than ever before.

But can unions mobilise outside labour? Are they capable of engagement in the ‘big conversation’ about alternatives to status quo thinking? It would require a change to ‘insider’ thinking—but that is precisely what the Accord did when pensioners and poverty became industrial issues. It would require confronting the anti-environmental image unions have had—but already many unions are actively engaged in environmental and climate issues, in activities ranging from workplace ‘climate heroes’ to regional development alliances with environmental groups through to a remarkably active stance in tackling climate change issues by the coal miners union (Australian Council of Trade Unions 2011; Snell, Fairbrother & Hart 2009; Australian Conservation Foundation 2008; CFMEU Mining & Energy Division 2011).

Indeed, unions are probably the only group in Australia with the resources, the breadth of membership, and the organising capability to draw together the disparate groups and the individuals concerned with developing an alternative. In that way, they could be central to the solution.

In the end, if unions are to be part of the solution, there is much to be done. It requires action in developing and empowering workplace delegates and members, democratising processes with unions, strengthening articulations between levels, developing better framing capabilities, managing governance properly, becoming learning organisations, deepening links and networks with other organisations and movements in the community and civil society, and using such links to develop and articulate an alternative vision of society that reflects progressive values. It is a huge task. But if unions do not do this, who will?

REFERENCES

Anxo, D., Franz, C. & Kümmerling, A. 2012, Working time and work–life balance in a life course perspective, a report based on the fifth European Working Conditions Survey, Eurofound, Dublin [Online], Available: http://eurofound.europa.eu/sites/default/files/ef_publication/field_ef_document/ef1273en.pdf [2015, Feb 6].

Atkinson, A.B. & Leigh, A. 2007, ‘The distribution of top incomes in Australia’, Economic Record, vol. 83, no. 262, pp. 247–261.

Australian Bureau of Statistics 2014, Employee Earnings, Benefits and Trade Union Membership, Australia, Cat. no. 6310.0, Australian Bureau of Statistics, Canberra.

Australian Conservation Foundation 2008, ACF and QPSU unite for climate heroes campaign, Media release, 18 March [Online], Available: http://www.acfonline.org.au/news-media/media-release/acf-and-qpsu-unite-climate-heroes-campaign [2015, Feb 6].

Australian Council of Trade Unions 2011, Climate Change is Union Business, ACTU, Melbourne.

Baker, D., Johnson, M. & Denniss, R. 2014, Walking the tightrope: Have Australians achieved work/life balance?, Policy Brief,  The Australia Institute, Canberra.

Bandura, A. 1995, ‘Exercise of personal and collective efficacy in changing societies’, in Self-efficacy in Changing Societies, ed. A. Bandura, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 1–45.

Bandura, A. 1997, Self-efficacy: The Exercise of Control, W.H. Freeman & Company, New York.

Brunori, P., Ferreira, F.H.G. & Peragine, V. 2013, Inequality of opportunity, income inequality and economic mobility: Some international comparisons, in Policy Research Working Paper No. 6304, World Bank, Development Research Group, Poverty and Inequality Team, Washington DC.

Callaghan, G. & Thompson, P. 2001, ‘Edwards revisited: Technical control and call centres’, Economic and Industrial Democracy, vol. 22, no. 1, pp. 13–37.

Campbell, I. 2002, ‘Extended working hours in Australia’, Labour and Industry, vol. 13, no. 1, pp. 91–110.

Campbell, I. & Burgess, J. 2001, ‘Casual employment in Australia and temporary employment in Europe: Developing a cross-national comparison’, Work, Employment and Society, vol. 15, no. 1, pp. 171–184.

Card, D., Lemieux, T. & Riddell, W.C. 2003, Unionization and wage inequality: A comparative study of the US, the UK, and Canada, NBER Working Paper No. 9473, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA [Online], Available: http://www.nber.org/papers/w9473 [2015, Feb 6].

CFMEU Mining & Energy Division 2011, Why a price on carbon is essential for our future, Construction, Forestry, Mining & Energy Union [Online], Available: http://cfmeu.com.au/sites/cfmeu.com.au/files/downloads/%5Bfield_download_state-raw.pdf [2015, Feb 6].

Charlwood, A. 2007, ‘The de-collectivisation of pay setting in Britain 1990–98: Incidence, determinants and impact’, Industrial Relations Journal, vol. 38, no. 1, pp. 33–50.

Crook, A. 2013, ‘Education union’s $1m Greens splash drives division in ranks’, Crikey, 20 June [Online], Available: http://www.crikey.com.au/2013/06/20/education-unions-1m-greens-splash-drives-division-in-ranks/?wpmp_switcher=mobile [2015, Feb 6].

Daley, P. 2010, ‘Labor needs detente with the Greens’, The Sydney Morning Herald, 15 May [Online], Available: http://www.smh.com.au/federal-politics/political-opinion/labor-needs-detente-with-the-greens-20100514-v5bf.html [2015, Feb 6].

Denniss, R. & Baker, D. 2012, An unhealthy obsession? The impact of work hours and workplace culture on Australia’s health, Institute Paper No. 11, The Australia Institute, Canberra.

Ellis, L. & Smith, K. 2007, The global upward trend in the profit share, BIS Working Paper No. 231, Bank for International Settlements, Basel.

Essential Media Communications 2015, ‘Trust in institutions’, The Essential Report, 20 January [Online], Available: http://essentialvision.com.au/documents/essential_report_150120.pdf [2015, Feb 6].

Freeman, R.B. 2005, Can unions close the unfilled demand for representation and participation in the US?, Unpublished paper, Harvard University and NBER.

Freeman, R.B. & Medoff, J.L. 1984, What Do Unions Do?, Basic Books, New York.

Frydman, C. & Saks, R.E. 2005, Historical trends in executive compensation 1936–2003, ChicagoBooth Economics Workshop, University of Chicago, Booth School of Economics, Chicago.

Gage, B. 2014, ‘Should you care about the fate of unions?’, Slate, 30 June [Online], Available: http://www.slate.com/articles/news_and_politics/history/2014/06/supreme_court_harris_decision.html [2015, Feb 6].

Gordon, M. 2014, ‘Royal commissioner who pursued Julia Gillard can’t answer the biggest question’, The Age, 19 December.

Green, F. 2004, ‘Why has work effort become more intense?’, Industrial Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society, vol. 43, no. 4, pp. 709–741.

Griffith Work Time Project 2003, Working time transformations and effects, Queensland Department of Industrial Relations, Brisbane.

Hoque, K. & Bacon, N. 2014, ‘Unions, joint regulation and workplace equality policy and practice in Britain: Evidence from the 2004 Workplace Employment Relations Survey’, Work, Employment and Society, vol. 28, no. 2, pp. 265–284.

International Monetary Fund 2013, World Economic Outlook Database, New York.

Kapur, A., Macleod, N. & Singh, N. 2005, ‘Plutonomy: Buying luxury, explaining global imbalances’, Citigroup Equity Strategy Industry Note, 16 October.

Krueger, A.B. 2012, The rise and consequences of inequality, Council of Economic Advisers, Washington DC [Online], Available: http://milescorak.files.wordpress.com/2012/01/speech-2012_01_12_final_web-1.pdf [2015, Feb 6].

LabourStart 2014, LabourStart Australia [Online], Available: http://www.labourstart.org/2013/country.php?country=Australia&langcode=en [2015, Feb 6].

Lévesque, C. & Murray, G. 2002, ‘Local versus global: Activating local union power in the global economy’, Labor Studies Journal, vol. 27, no. 3, pp. 39–65.

Lévesque, C. & Murray, G. 2010, ‘Understanding union power: Resources and capabilities for renewing union capacity’, TransferEuropean Review of Labour and Research, vol. 16, no. 3, pp. 333–350.

Lyons, T. 2014, ‘The royal commission into trade unions is a political witch hunt’, Guardian 28 July.

McConville, C. 2000, ‘The Australian waterfront dispute 1998’, Politics and Society, vol. 28, no. 3, pp. 393–412.

Mishel, L., Bernstein, J. & Shierholz, H. 2009, State of Working America 2008/2009, Economic Policy Institute, Washington DC.

Mishel, L. & Walters, M. 2003, How unions help all workers, Briefing Paper, Economic Policy Institute, Washington DC.

Muir, K. 2008, Worth Fighting For: Inside the Your Rights at Work Campaign, University of NSW Press, Sydney.

Muir, K. & Peetz, D. 2010, ‘Not dead yet: The Australian union movement and the defeat of a government’, Social Movement Studies, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 215–228.

Murray, G. & Peetz, D. 2013, ‘Plutonomy and the one per cent’, in Challenging the Orthodoxy: Reflections on Frank Stilwell’s Contribution to Political Economy, eds S. Schroeder & L. Chester, Springer, New York, pp. 129–148.

Nissen, B. & Jarley, P. 2005, ‘Unions as social capital: Renewal through a return to the logic of mutual aid?’, Labor Studies Journal, vol. 29, no. 4, pp. 1–26.

Noah, T. 2010, ‘The United States of inequality’, Slate, 12 September [Online], Available: http://www.slate.com/articles/news_and_politics/the_great_divergence/features/2010/the_united_states_of_inequality.html [2015, Feb 6].

Nolan, R. 2014, ‘The ETU is nobody’s friend’, Brisbane Times, 6 March [Online], Available: http://www.brisbanetimes.com.au/comment/the-etu-is-nobodys-friend-20140306-3495o.html [2015, Feb 6].

O’Connor, S. 2013, ‘Amazon unpacked’, Financial Times, 8 February.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 1997, ‘Economic Performance and the Structure of Collective Bargaining’, Economic Outlook 1996, OECD, Paris, pp. 63–92.

Peetz, D. 1998, Unions in a Contrary World: The Future of the Australian Trade Union Movement, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Peetz, D. 1999, ‘Nearly the year of living dangerously: In the emerging worlds of Australian industrial relations’, Asia Pacific Journal of Human Resources, vol. 37, no. 2, pp. 3–23.

Peetz, D. 2002, ‘Sympathy for the devil? Attitudes to Australian unions’, Australian Journal of Political Science, vol. 37, no. 1, pp. 57–80.

Peetz, D. 2012, ‘Does industrial relations policy affect productivity?’, Australian Bulletin of Labour, vol. 38, no. 4, pp. 268–292.

Peetz, D. & Alexander, M. 2013, ‘A synthesis of research on training of union delegates’, Industrial Relations Journal, vol. 44, no. 4, pp. 425–442.

Peetz, D. & Bailey, J. 2011, ‘Neoliberal evolution and union responses in Australia’, in International Handbook on Labour Unions: Responses to Neo-liberalism, eds G. Gall, A. Wilkinson & R. Hurd, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp. 62–81.

Peetz, D. & Bailey, J. 2012, ‘Dancing alone: The Australian union movement over three decades’, Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 54, no. 4, pp. 524–541.

Peetz, D. & Pocock, B. 2007, ‘Community activists, coalitions and unionism’, in Trade Unions in the Community: Values, Issues, Shared Interests and Alliances, eds D. Buttigieg, S. Cockfield, R. Cooney, M. Jerrard & A. Rainnie, Heidelberg Books, Adelaide.

Peetz, D. & Pocock, B. 2009, ‘An analysis of workplace representatives, union power and democracy in Australia’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 47, no. 4, pp. 623–652.

Peetz, D., Webb, C. & Jones, M. 2002, ‘Activism amongst workplace union delegates’, International Journal of Employment Studies, vol. 10, no. 2, pp. 83–108.

Piketty, T. 2014, Capital in the Twenty-First Century, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA.

Pocock, B. 1998, ‘Institutional sclerosis: Prospects for trade union transformation’, Labour & Industry, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 17–33.

Pocock, B., Skinner, N. & Ichii, R. 2009, Work, life & workplace flexibility: The Australian Work and Life Index 2009, Centre for Work + Life, University of South Australia, Adelaide.

Pontusson, J. 2013, ‘Unionization, Inequality and Redistribution’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 51, no. 4, pp. 797–825.

Quiggin, J. 2010, Zombie Economics, Princeton University Press, New Jersey.

Quiggin, J. 2014, ‘How Thomas Piketty found a mass audience, and what it means for public policy’, Inside Story, 30 May [Online], Available: http://insidestory.org.au/how-thomas-piketty-found-a-mass-audience-and-what-it-means-for-public-policy [2015, Feb 6].

Rafferty, M. & Yu, S. 2010, Shifting risk: Work and working life in Australia, A report for the Australian Council of Trade Unions, Workplace Research Centre, The University of Sydney, Sydney.

Roy Morgan Research 2014, Roy Morgan Image of Professions Survey 2014 – Nurses still most highly regarded – followed by doctors, pharmacists & high court judges, Morgan Poll, Finding No. 5531, Sydney [Online], Available: http://www.roymorgan.com.au/findings/5531-image-of-professions-2014-201404110537 [2015, Feb 6].

Rudd, K. & Gillard, J. 2007, Forward with Fairness: Labor’s Plan for Fairer and More Productive Australian Workplaces, Australian Labor Party, Canberra.

Schneiders, B. 2014, ‘Failure to deal with Kathy Jackson undermines credibility of Royal Commission’, The Age, 19 December [Online], Available: http://www.theage.com.au/national/failure-to-deal-with-kathy-jackson-undermines-credibility-of-royal-commission-20141219-12aof9.html [2015, Feb 6].

Shenker-Osorio, A. 2012, Don’t Buy It: The Trouble with Talking Nonsense about the Economy, Public Affairs, New York.

Shepanski, P. & Diamond, M. 2007, An unexpected tragedy: Evidence for the connection between working patterns and family breakdown in Australia, Relationships Forum Australia, Sydney [Online], Available: http://www.relationshipsforum.org.au/assets/downloads/rfa_an_unexpected_tragedy_main_report.pdf [2015, Feb 6].

Skinner, N. & Pocock, B. 2014, The persistent challenge: Living, working and caring in Australia in 2014, The Australian Work and Life Index 2014, Centre for Work + Life, University of South Australia, Adelaide.

Snell, D., Fairbrother, P. & Hart, A. 2009, ‘Blue-green alliances: Union capacities and prospects as environmental actors’, in The Future of Sociology: The Australian Sociological Association 2009 Annual Conference, eds S. Lockie, D. Bissell, A. Grieg, M. Hyenes, D. Marsh, L. Saha, J. Sikora & D. Woodman, The Australian Sociological Association, Canberra.

Standing, G. 2011, The Precariat: The New, Dangerous Class, Bloomsbury Academic, London.

Stilwell, F. & Jordan, K. 2007, Who Gets What? Analysing Economic Inequality in Australia, Cambridge University Press, Melbourne.

Tattersall, A. 2010, Power in Coalition: Strategies for Strong Unions and Social Change, Cornell University Press, Ithaca NY.

Tourish, D., Collinson, D. & Barker, J.R. 2009, ‘Manufacturing conformity: Leadership through coercive persuasion in business organisations’, M@n@gement, vol. 12, no. 5, pp. 360–383.

Van den Broek, D. 1997, ‘Human resource management, workforce control and union avoidance: An Australian case study’, Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 39, no. 3, pp. 332–48.

Wade, R.H. 2014, ‘The Piketty phenomenon and the future of inequality’, Real-world Economics Review, vol. 69, pp. 2–17.

Western, B. & Rosenfeld, J. 2011, ‘Unions, norms, and the rise in U.S. wage inequality’, American Sociological Review, vol. 76, no. 4, pp. 513–537.

White, A. 2010, Social media for unions, Aleithia Media and Communications, Melbourne [Online], Available: http://alexwhite.org/shop/social-media-for-unions/ [2015, Feb 6].

Willmott, R.G. & Pickett, K. 2009, The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better, Allen Lane, London.

Willmott, H. 1993, ‘Strength is ignorance; slavery is freedom: Managing culture in modern organizations’, The Journal of Management Studies, vol. 30, no. 4, pp. 515–52.

Wilson, S. & Spies-Butcher, B. 2011, ‘When labour makes a difference: Union mobilization and the 2007 federal election in Australia’, British Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 49, no. 2, pp. 306–331.

Wiseman, J. 1998, ‘Here to stay? The 1997–1998 Australian waterfront dispute and its implications’, Labour and Industry, vol. 99, no. 1, pp. 1–16.

Workplace Express 2014, ‘Senior cop backs down from “union bikie” claim’, Workplace Express, 18 September [Online], Available: https://secure.workplaceexpress.com.au/nl06_news_selected.php?selkey=52719 [2015, Feb 6].

Wright, C. & Lund, J. 1996, ‘Best practice Taylorism: “Yankee speed-up” in Australian grocery distribution’, Journal of Industrial Relations, vol. 38, no. 2, pp. 196–212.

David Peetz is Professor of Employment Relations and a member of the Centre for Work, Organisation and Wellbeing at Griffith University.